Alumni Interview series: CHOICE recent graduate Nathaniel Hendrix

posted by Sara Khor

We are starting a series of interviews with graduates from the CHOICE Institute, and are very excited to have Nathaniel Hendrix, who graduated from the PhD program in 2020, share his experience with us.

“Grad school is like training a pet, where the pet is your own mind… You have to be intentional about figuring out what you want to teach yourself and how you’re going to do it.”

Nathaniel Hendrix
  1. Why did you choose to do a PhD?  How did you choose health economics?

I entered the PhD program directly after graduating with my PharmD. I went into my clinical training imagining that almost all of our decisions were grounded in a solid basis of evidence. But once I learned to read studies for myself, I began to see how complex the processes of gathering and evaluating evidence really were. This made me a bit hung up on how clinicians make decisions and how they can learn to make them better.

I had always been pretty indulgent with myself about taking electives during my PharmD training. I’d explored computer science and philosophy of science, but when I started taking classes in health economics, that gave me a vocabulary for talking and thinking about decision-making that I hadn’t been able to find before. At the same time, it’s a relatively young field and a very interdisciplinary one, so it felt to me like I could impact the direction of the field and that my curiosity about exploring different ideas would be rewarded.

2. What was the topic of your PhD?

My dissertation was on using health economics tools to solve translational issues in artificial intelligence (AI). It had two separate aims. First, I conducted a discrete choice experiment to see what primary care providers see as valuable in how AI could be used for breast cancer screening. Most women who take part in breast cancer screening make the decision to start with their primary care providers, so these providers have an outsized role to play in determining how AI will be used for breast cancer screening. We found that there were multiple ways that developers can appeal to primary care providers with their AI products: by improving sensitivity, by having a well-thought-out workflow that includes radiologists, and by having highly diverse training data.

The second aim had to do with using cost-effectiveness analysis to inform how AI algorithms are used for breast cancer screening. We used a real set of AI algorithms that had been submitted to a contest and used different methods of selecting a sensitivity/specificity threshold at which they could operate. Our model ended up selecting very similar thresholds as other heuristic methods, but it taught me a lot about the challenges of using cost-effectiveness analysis on AI.

“Write down every research idea that you have, and revisit that list frequently. Half of the ideas will be terrible in retrospect, but that’s okay.”

3. What are you currently working on?  Does this align with your training or your research interests?

After my PhD, I started a postdoc at the Harvard T.H. Chan School of Public Health, where I’m mostly studying cost-effectiveness methodology. I have three main projects right now. First, I’m working on developing methods for integrating financial risk protection into decisions about prioritizing healthcare interventions in low- and middle-income countries. Healthcare plays a major role in keeping people out of poverty, but this isn’t acknowledged in conventional cost-effectiveness analysis.

Next, I’m working on methods for assessing the cost-effectiveness of health system strengthening interventions, such as building new facilities, training personnel, or developing a new informatics infrastructure. This is challenging because these long-term projects, which almost everyone acknowledges as important, have to compete for funding against urgent needs like making more medicines available or expanding vaccinations.

Finally, I’m completing a project about how to use Deep Learning-based breast cancer risk scores to personalize screening. Even though breast cancer screening reduces cancer mortality, there are many downsides because the false-positive rate is pretty high in screening. So we’re hoping we can use AI to determine who is most likely to benefit from screening and who might have a higher risk of being harmed.

I see this last project as most connected to my PhD research, because I’m using many of the same techniques that I used in the second aim of my dissertation. But I’m also learning many methods like constrained optimization that aren’t emphasized at UW but that are important when thinking about operating a healthcare system efficiently. Of course, I’m also wrapping up several projects I started during my time at UW, so there’s some continuity there too.

4.  What are some of the things you wish you’d known when you started your PhD?

I wish I had had a better system for keeping track of the things I was reading. Ultimately, I missed the opportunity for making connections because it took me until I was well into my dissertation to discover the tools I needed for taking notes and helping myself to rediscover ideas I’d read in the past. For me, this ended up being the Zettelkasten system, which I use on the website Roam Research (read Sönke Ahrens’s book, “How to take smart notes,” for more info on this!).

5. Can you share one of your favorite or proudest moments during the PhD years?

Probably my proudest moment was when I found out that I had gotten a PhRMA Foundation fellowship for my dissertation. I was on vacation in San Francisco, waiting out an afternoon rainstorm in a café when I got the call, and it was really a pivotal moment for me. I had been feeling a bit of imposter syndrome about my dissertation, but to know that these other researchers had found my ideas exciting enough to fund was a huge boost of confidence.

“I’m convinced that you can’t be a good researcher without learning to be a good reader.”

6. What do you think are the “secret sauces” of a successful PhD experience?

Completing a PhD program is a great chance to explore. I didn’t quite understand this when I went into it and felt pressured (by myself, really!) to focus more on one area or another. Once I started just saying yes to every experience I had time for, I started to learn a lot more. This meant not just learning more about different technical matters, but also learning about what sort of work styles and communication styles I’m most comfortable with. That’s super important, because our work is usually so collaborative.

As you go through a PhD program and learn more, what’s expected from you also changes. In the beginning, you’re soaking up new methods and concepts, so you end up doing a lot of work on tasks like data cleaning or literature review that are really time consuming but necessary. With more experience, you should be able to start making suggestions to your collaborators about the directions for your work. And then finally, with your dissertation, you get a lot more independence about its direction.

Part of this development process is having good reading habits. That means keeping track of what journals are publishing so that you have a sense of what current conversations are happening. And then, again, finding ways to make connections between what you read. Ultimately, I’m convinced that you can’t be a good researcher without learning to be a good reader.

7. What do you think is the best metaphor for your grad school experience?  How would you complete this sentence: “Grad school is like…”

Grad school is like training a pet, where the pet is your own mind. During grad school, you’ll have to teach yourself a lot of new skills, so it’s important to think about how to keep yourself motivated. It’s also vital to learn to recognize when you’re tired and need to do something entertaining. But overall, you have to be intentional about figuring out what you want to teach yourself and how you’re going to do it.

8.    Do you have any other advice for current/future PhD students?

Write down every research idea that you have, and revisit that list frequently. Half of the ideas will be terrible in retrospect, but that’s okay. It’s easier to come up with good ideas if you come up with lots of ideas. And, again, to come up with ideas, it’s important to cultivate a very intentional habit of reading academic literature.

Also, I would encourage students to publish broadly. Look at the areas where they’re doing projects, compare it to the major areas in the CHOICE curriculum, and see if there are any weaknesses. You’ll have a lot more flexibility with your job search if you publish broadly. One way to do this is to collaborate with a lot of different people who are working in different areas.

Medicare Advantage for All – A Conversation with Chuck Phelps

by Sara Khor, Yilin Chen, and Joyce Jiang

From left to right:  Brennan Beal, Joyce Jiang, Yilin Chen, Jacinda Tran, Sara Khor, Charles Phelps

The coronavirus disease 2019 (COVID-19) pandemic has shone a spotlight on the shortcomings of the current US health care system.  There is an urgent need to address the problems with healthcare access, costs, and equity.  Conversations related to health care reform have been and will continue to be front and center in the upcoming presidential election.  Many health care reform proposals have been put forward, including the expansion of the Affordable Care Act, Medicare-for-All, and Medicare expansion that maintains a role for private insurers.

Earlier this year, Dr. Charles Phelps, a renowned health economist and the author of the Health Economics textbook, visited the CHOICE Institute and gave a lecture on his proposed health care plan: Medicare-Advantage-for-All.  Under this proposal, all permanent residents will be able to choose among a wide variety of private insurance plans, similar to the Medicare Advantage program that is currently available to the older US population.  All individuals will have health care coverage, with the minimum coverage being a high-deductible health plan with a health savings account.  The health savings account can be filled up based on income levels.  High value care such as preventative medicine can bypass the deductible.

We had the honor of sitting down with Dr. Phelps to talk more about his proposal. 

Part 1 – On health care costs:

What are the most important drivers of the current cost growth in the healthcare system?

Dr. Phelps identified two main drivers of the healthcare cost growth:  introduction of new technologies and the aging population.  In the long run, he said, the introduction of new technologies, which includes diagnostic tools, pharmaceuticals, and genetic-based medicine, will increase costs.  As treatment and drugs become more targeted, they will be sold in smaller quantities for focused populations.  While these new advances will produce a lot of value, they will also drive cost growth. 

As the size of the older population continues to expand, the age distribution pyramid (where the bottom is the youngest age group and the top is the oldest) will be shaped more like a cylinder. “When you look 20 years from now, this cylinder is going to have a great big hat on,” says Dr. Phelps.  “The widest group on this cylinder… is going to be the oldest group at the top”. 

This has important implication for healthcare costs, because the current way we are financing Medicare is through the payroll tax.  The ratio of workers (who pay the payroll tax) to retired individuals (who use Medicare) is shrinking.  “At the beginning of Medicare, this ratio was 4.5,” says Dr. Phelps.  “In a couple of decades, this ratio is going to be 2 workers per retiree.  The payroll tax mechanism of paying for Medicare has to change”.

How would the Medicare Advantage-for-All Plan address these cost drivers?

In a single payer system, usually one agency (e.g. CMS in Medicare) makes the determination about which new technology to introduce into the system.  “They can make mistakes both by being too generous, letting too many things in the door, or being too stingy,” said Dr. Phelps.  According to Dr. Phelps, the current US Medicare system is too generous, as it has not built in any cost constraints, while the British National Health Service has very tight cost-effective criteria for approval of new technologies.

The Medicare-Advantage-for-All plan would allow different plans to make cost-effectiveness evaluations.  The exact details of the plan still need to be decided, but Dr. Phelps said that technologies that are very cost-effective, ICER between $50,000 to $75,000/quality-adjusted life year (QALY) gained, will be mandatory in the basic plan, and others will be left to the discretion of the insurance plan to cover it.  “People will buy insurance plans to fit their needs, just like they buy different cars with different degrees of safety and pizzazz.”

What is the potential cost impact of Medicare Advantage for all?   How is this cost impact compared to Medicare for All?

“Medicare-for-All is ghastly expensive, not because it offers universal health coverage, but because it eliminates all co-pays.”  The RAND Health Insurance experiment and the Oregon Health Insurance experiment have demonstrated that medical use will increase when there is no co-pay or deductible.  Dr. Phelps worried that the lack of co-pays will “unleash the monster in the evolution of new technologies,” referring to how moral hazard— the price sensitivity of demand for health care – may incentivize the use of low value care and technologies.  He was concerned that healthcare costs will continue to rise unless there is a very tight constraint on new technologies. 

In a way, Medicare-Advantage-for-All is similar to Medicare-for-All if everyone’s health saving account is filled up.  When determining how much should be in the health saving accounts, Dr. Phelps said that “it will be an experiment through time to trade off the risk bearing and cost control,”  adding that essential medicines and services, such as birth control or insulin for diabetes, can completely bypass the deductibles and co-pays. 

Right now, Dr. Phelps said it is unclear how the different program parameters should be set in order to balance costs, new technology introduction, and equity considerations, but he is trying to devise an instrument that would allow users the flexibility to tweak parameters over time.

How about administrative costs?  Dr. Phelps said that single payer plans, like Medicare-for-All, definitely reduce administrative costs. He argued that this administrative cost, although pricey, is giving us choice, and is controlling the costs by negotiating with providers about how much to pay for things instead of having fixed fee schedules.  “Our society really values choice,” Dr. Phelps added.  A one-size-fits-all plan takes away choice.  Using an analogy in car shopping, Dr. Phelps said having just one healthcare plan is like saying: “You can buy any car you want, as long as it is a Honda Accord.”

Instead of simply comparing the administrative costs between a single-payer government-funded plan and Medicare-Advantage-for-All plans, Dr. Phelps emphasized the importance of taking into account the welfare loss and tax distortions that arise from the increase of taxation in a single-payer government plan. “Every dollar of tax we collect distorts the economy in some fashion…If you raise income tax, you change the labor supply.”

Part 2 – On choices and health technology assessment (HTA):

If there are many Medicare-Advantage-for-All health plans and each plan uses a different threshold, how do consumers make informed decisions about which plans to choose?

“Advisors will emerge,” said Dr. Phelps. Like the advisors for buying automobiles or financial advisors for the stock market, Dr. Phelps believed that a service for advising people on healthcare insurance and utilization will develop, and so would competition.  These advisors could be independent or affiliated with big health plans.  The emergence of these advisors, he added, will “depend on having access to electronic medical records that people can share.”

What role will HTA play?  What role would an organization like the Institute for Clinical and Economic Review (ICER) play? 

 Dr. Phelps felt that the current way of conducting cost-effectiveness analyses is incomplete.  Individuals who want to maximize their own utility do not necessarily think about everything that the society thinks about.  While the QALY is a very important component of the overall value index, Phelps argued that the value index should include other things that are not necessarily built into a single individual’s utility, such as the fear of contagion and equitable distribution of health services.  “Policies about Ebola, Zika, and now the coronavirus, are not made on the cost-effectiveness of vaccines.  People would pay anything to get a coronavirus vaccine right now.  The fear of contagion dominates public discourse and public policies.  That is not captured in cost-effectiveness analysis.” 

Ideally, Dr. Phelps says, there will be competition among HTA organizations to produce estimates with quality control by the government, similar to how the FDA has control over the new drugs that come on to the market.  “I can see different insurance plans, [especially] some of the large ones, creating their own HTA shops.  ICER would continue and offer [assessments] to smaller insurance plans.” 

Part 3 – On equity:

Under Medicare-Advantage-for-All, multiple plans with varying premiums and deductibles mean that people who are better at navigating the system (e.g. more able to afford an advisor) or can afford the higher premiums may get more comprehensive care, potentially creating a situation where there is differential access and differential outcomes across the population based on education or wealth.  How should we think about this?

“A plan that has absolutely equal access to health care…is imaginary”.  Dr. Phelps argued that as long as people have different incomes, there would be differential care.  Even under the British National Health System, those who can pay more can seek additional or better care with private insurance.  In Ontario, Canada, where there is universal health coverage, some Canadians opt to purchase insurance to buy medical care in the U.S.  One thing that the Medicare-Advantage-for-All plan can guarantee, Dr. Phelps added, is minimal level of access to quality care for everyone.  The minimal plan could include an independent advisor.

How will international students be included in the plan?

International students are often in the U.S. for a few years.  They are not permanent residents, but they are also not temporary visitors.  It will be important that there are ways for these individuals to get access to the health plans.  Some suggestions that Dr. Phelps had were to charge individuals an actuarially-based fee to join the plans, or to negotiate bilateral exchanges with different nations. 

Part 4 — On political economy: 

What are some of the potential political pushbacks related to this proposal?

The country is very heavily divided between those who want a single-payer plan (e.g. Medicare-for-All) and those who want to continue with private insurance.  Those who are proponents of single-payer plans will not like Medicare-Advantage-for-All because it continues to use, as a central feature, and quite deliberately, private insurance plans.  In this political climate, Dr. Phelps said, “My forecast would be…that there is zero probability that a Medicare-for-All plan would pass through the congress.”

“The high deductible health plan creates some anxiety among some people…for two reasons”, he continued.  “One is that they say it discriminates against the poor.”  Dr. Phelps said he can completely eliminate this concern by filling up the health savings accounts on an income-related basis.  Another concern is that people in the high deductible plans will stop using the care that they need.  A short run fix, Dr. Phelps explained, is that all highly-valued services and medicines, like diabetes medications, bypass any deductible and copayment.   

“The long run fix is to vastly repair our vulnerable K-12 education system,” said Dr. Phelps. Higher education helps people navigate the highly complex health care system.  There is also a very steep education gradient on lifestyle choices that are bad for your health, like tobacco smoking and binge drinking.

Dr. Mark Bounthavong’s Talk on Formulating Good Research Questions

by Enrique M. Saldarriaga and Jacinda Tran

On April 16, 2020, the ISPOR Student Chapter at the University of Washington hosted a webinar on how to formulate good research questions featuring Dr. Mark Bounthavong, PhD, PharmD, MPH. He discussed aspects of compelling research questions, shared his formulating process, presented best practices, and provided recommendations for students at all stages of their career.

Dr. Bounthavong is a graduate of the UW CHOICE Institute and a prolific researcher with several years of experience in HEOR. He currently serves as a health economist at the VA Health Economics Resource Center and a Research Affiliate at Stanford University, and his research interests include pharmacoeconomics, outcomes research, health economics, process and program evaluations, econometric methods, and evidence synthesis using Bayesian methods.

Our UW Student Chapter thanks Dr. Bounthavong for his insightful presentation and hopes our fellow researchers find this recording of his presentation to be a helpful resource.

Note: Dr. Bounthavong has authorized the publication of his talk in this post.

Some challenges of working with claims databases

By Nathaniel Hendrix

Real-world evidence has become increasingly important as a data source for comparative effectiveness research, drug safety research, and adherence studies, among other types of research. In addition to sources such as electronic medical records, mobile data, and disease registries, much of the real-world evidence we use comes from large claims databases like Truven Health MarketScan or IQVIA, which record patients’ insurance claims for services and drugs. The enormous size of these databases means that researchers can detect subtle safety signals or study rare conditions where they may not have been able to previously.

Using these databases is not without its challenges, though. In this article, I’ll be discussing a few challenges that I’ve encountered as I’ve worked with faculty on a claims database project in the past year. It’s important for researchers to be aware of these limitations, as they necessarily inform our understanding of how claims-based studies should be designed and interpreted.

Challenge #1: Treatment selection bias

Treatment selection bias occurs when patients are assigned to treatment based on some characteristic that also affects the outcome of interest. If patients with more severe disease are assigned to Drug A rather than Drug B, patients using Drug A may have worse outcomes and we might conclude that Drug B is more effective. Alternatively, if patients with a certain comorbidity are preferentially prescribed a different drug than those patients without the comorbidity – an example of channeling bias – we may conclude that this drug is associated with this comorbidity.

These conclusions would be too hasty, though. What we’d like to do is to simulate a randomized trial, where patients are assigned to treatment without regard for their personal characteristics. Methods such as propensity scores give us this option, but these methods often unavailable to researchers working with claims data. This is because many disease characteristics are not recorded in claims data.

An example might clarify this: imagine that you’re trying to assess the effect of HAART (highly active anti-retroviral therapy) on mortality in HIV patients. Disease characteristics such as CD4 count would be associated with both use of HAART and mortality, but are not recorded in claims data. We could adjust our analysis for other factors such as age and time since diagnosis, but our result would be biased. It’s important, therefore, to understand whether any covariates affect both treatment assignment and the outcome of interest, and to consider other data sources (such as disease registries) if they do.

Challenge #2: Claims data don’t include how the prescription was written

The nature of pharmacy claims data is to record when patients pick up their medications. This creates excellent opportunities for studying resource use and adherence, but these data, unfortunately, lack information about when and how the prescription for these medications was written.

One effect of this is that we don’t know how much time passes between a drug’s being prescribed and when it’s first used. Clearly, if several months pass between the initial prescription and a patient finally picking up that drug from the pharmacy, that would be time spent in non-adherence. We’re not able to capture that time, though. In the case of primary non-adherence, where a prescription is written for a drug that is never picked up at all, this behavior cannot be detected, potentially interfering with our ability to understand the causes of adverse outcomes and to assess the need for interventions that can improve adherence.

Challenge #3: Errors in days’ supply

Days’ supply is essential for calculating adherence and resource use, but errors sometimes appear that can be difficult to work with. Sometimes these are clear entry errors. For example, if a technician enters 310 days instead of 30 days. The payer usually rejects claims made with unusual days’ supply, but some such claims remain in the database.

Another issue is that certain errors in the days’ supply of drugs can be impossible to interpret. For example, if a drug is usually dispensed with an 84-day supply (i.e., 12 weeks) and a claim appears that has a 48-day supply, it’s impossible to know whether the prescriber had escalated the dose or the pharmacy staff had accidentally entered the days’ supply incorrectly. This is one of several reasons why it’s important to carefully consider imposing restrictions on the days’ supply for claims if this parameter is relevant to your research.

Errors such as these can significantly impact analyses that work with days’ supply of prescriptions, so it’s essential to be proactive about looking for cases where the days’ supply is not realistic or interpretable. Consider setting a realistic range to truncate days’ supply before you undertake your analysis.

Challenge #4: Generalizing results from claims studies can be difficult

Claims databases are usually grouped by insurance type. For example, the commercial claims database only contains encounters by commercially-insured patients and their dependents while excluding patients insured by Medicare and/or Medicaid. They may also only include Medicare patients with supplementary insurance. Separating these populations into different databases can make it difficult and sometimes unaffordable for researchers to produce generalizable results as well as introducing complexity due to the need for merging databases.

These populations are all quite different from each other: commercially-insured enrollees are generally healthier than Medicaid enrollees of the same age. And the “dual-eligibles” – enrollees in both Medicare and Medicaid – are different from individuals enrolled in just one of these programs. Since it’s costly and sometimes infeasible to capture all of these patients in a single analysis, you may need to hone your research question carefully so it can be answered by a single database instead of trying to access them all. Fortunately, sampling weights are now common, which helps generalize within your age and insurance grouping even if they are somewhat cumbersome to work with.

In summary, claims databases have added immeasurable value to several fields of research by collecting information on the real-world behavior of clinicians and patients. Still, there are some significant challenges that need to be taken into account when considering using claims data. Finding a good scientific question that suits these data means understanding their limitations. These are a few of the most important ones, but anyone who works with these data long enough will be sure to discover challenges unique to their own research program.

Updated estimates of cost-effectiveness for plaque psoriasis treatments

Along with co-authors from ICER and The CHOICE Institute, I recently published a paper in JMCP titled, “Cost-effectiveness of targeted pharmacotherapy for moderate-to-severe plaque psoriasis.” In this publication, we sought to update estimates of cost-effectiveness for systemic therapies useful in the population of patients with psoriasis for whom methotrexate and phototherapy are not enough.

Starting in 1998, a class of drugs acting on Tumor Necrosis Factor alpha (TNFɑ) has been the mainstay of psoriasis treatment in this population. The drugs in this class, including adalimumab, etanercept, and infliximab, are still widely used due to their long history of safety and lower cost than some competitors. They are less effective than many new treatments, however, particularly drugs inhibiting interleukin-17 such as brodalumab, ixekizumab, and secukinumab.

This presents a significant challenge to decision-makers: is it better to initiate targeted treatment with a less effective, less costly option, or a more effective, costlier one? We found that the answer to this question is complicated by several current gaps in knowledge. First, there is some evidence that prior exposure to biologic drugs is associated with lower effectiveness in subsequent biologics. This means that the selection of a first targeted treatment must balance cost considerations with the possibility of losing effectiveness in subsequent targeted treatments if the first is not effective.

A related issue is that the duration of effectiveness (or “drug survival”) for each of these drugs is currently poorly characterized in the US context. Drug discontinuation and switching is significantly impacted by policy considerations such as requirements for step therapy and restrictions on dose escalation. Therefore, while there is a reasonable amount of research about drug survival in Europe, it is not clear how well this information translates to the US.

Another difficulty of performing cost-effectiveness research in this disease area is the difficulty of mapping utility weights onto trial outcomes. Every drug considered in our analysis used percentage change in the Psoriasis Area Severity Index (PASI) over baseline. Because this is not an absolute measure, it required that we assume that patients have comparable baseline PASI scores between studies. In other words, we had to assume that a given percent improvement in PASI was equivalent to a given increase in health-related quality of life. This means that if one study’s population had less severe psoriasis at baseline, we probably overstated the utility benefit of that drug.

In light of these gaps in knowledge, our analytic strategy was to model a simulated cohort of patients with incident use of targeted drugs. After taking a first targeted drug, they could be switched to a second targeted drug or cease targeted therapy. We made the decision to limit patients to two lines of targeted treatment in order to keep the paper focused on the issue of initial treatment.

pso cost effectiveness frontier

What we found is a nuanced picture of cost-effectiveness in this disease area. In agreement with older cost-effectiveness studies, we found that infliximab is the most cost-effective TNFɑ drug and, along with the PDE-4 inhibitor apremilast, is likely to be the most cost-effective treatment at lower willingness-to-pay (WTP) thresholds. However, at higher WTP thresholds of $150,000 per quality-adjusted life year and above, we found that the IL-17 inhibitors brodalumab and secukinumab become more likely to be the most cost-effective.

The ambiguity of these results suggests both the importance of closing the gaps in knowledge mentioned above and of considering factors beyond cost-effectiveness in coverage decisions. For example, apremilast is the only oral drug we considered and patients may be willing to trade lower effectiveness to avoid injections. Another consideration is that IL-17 inhibitors are contraindicated for patients with inflammatory bowel disease, suggesting that payers should make a variety of drug classes accessible in order to provide for all patients.

In summary, these results should be seen as provisional, not only because many important parameters are still uncertain, but also because several new drugs and biosimilars for plaque psoriasis are nearing release. Decision-makers will need to keep an eye on emerging evidence in order to make rational decisions about this costly and impactful class of drugs.